8 Reasons
to Ignore the New Central Bank Gold Agreement
James Turk
GoldMoney
March 17, 2004
On March 8th
the European Central Bank and 14 of Europe's national central
banks made the following
announcement:
"In the
interest of clarifying their intentions with respect to their
gold holdings, the undersigned institutions make the following
statement:
1. Gold will remain an important element of global monetary reserves.
2. The gold sales already decided and to be decided by the undersigned
institutions will be achieved through a concerted programme of
sales over a period of five years, starting on 27 September 2004,
just after the end of the previous agreement. Annual sales will
not exceed 500 tons and total sales over this period will not
exceed 2,500 tons.
3. Over this period, the signatories to this agreement have agreed
that the total amount of their gold leasings and the total amount
of their use of gold futures and options will not exceed the
amounts prevailing at the date of the signature of the previous
agreement.
4. This agreement will be reviewed after five years."
This statement contains only 147 words, and it appears simple
and straightforward enough on the surface. The central banks
even tell us the reason for their statement - to 'clarify their
intentions.' Wow, aren't they swell guys. But don't be deceived.
Central banks deserve our scorn, and for that matter, our enmity
too for the interventionist, statist policies that they inflict
upon us in order to sustain the fiat currency that they create,
which the politicians then debase to our detriment.
To truly understand the significance of any central bank pronouncement,
one has to read between the lines.
Here's how I read their statement:
(1) Central banks only tell you what they want you to hear. If
this premise weren't true, they would not keep the public in
the dark by holding meetings in secret and then redacting the
minutes. They would not report on their balance sheets 'gold
in the vault' and 'gold on loan' as one line item, in obvious
disregard for generally accepted accounting principles. So when
central banks say that they want to 'clarify their intentions',
it is prudent to be skeptical - suspicious even - because that
is not the way they operate. They operate in secret, and any
pretense of openness is just a sham.
(2) As a corollary to #1 above, central banks are transparent
only when it serves their interest, and are transparent only
to the extent that shedding some light on a matter in fact helps
obfuscate their true intent. In other words, they tell half-truths,
and then let people draw their own - usually wrong - conclusions
from the central bank's statement. For example, although the
Bank of England signed the first central bank gold agreement
in September 1999, they did not sign this one because according
to a statement released after the new agreement was announced,
"Britain did not INTEND to sell any gold during
the period covered by the deal" [emphasis added].
Sounds plausible
enough at first blush, but hey, wasn't the purpose of this new
agreement to 'clarify' central bank intentions? So if the BoE
does not intend to sell any gold during this period as they say,
then why not sign the agreement? Clearly, other forces are at
work here, so they disclose to the public a half-truth. If their
aim was to provide the whole truth, the Bank of England would
have declared that they did not sign the agreement because there
is a reasonable probability that their present intentions may
change before the agreement expires in five years, or they otherwise
did not want their hands tied during this period because there
were other aspects to the agreement to which they did not agree.
(3) There are several things the Bank of England may not have
found acceptable. Even though they took a bath on their gold
disposals a few years ago when gold fetched a much lower rate
of exchange to the dollar and other currencies than it does today,
maybe they want to sell what little they have left. Or perhaps
they want to lease more gold, or use futures and options in amounts
greater than those "amounts prevailing at the date of
the signature of the previous agreement." The Bank of
England plays a pivotal role in the effort by central banks to
manage gold's rate of exchange to national currencies, and the
Bank of England apparently did not want its hands tied. We can
assume that if they allowed that to happen, the Bank of England's
pivotal role in the gold price management scheme would somehow
be impaired. It is therefore logical to conclude from the Bank
of England's self-imposed exclusion from this new agreement that
central banks intend to keep trying to hold down the gold price,
regardless of this agreement.
(4) Given the decline in hedging by mining companies since September
1999, the amounts of leasing, futures and options outstanding
when the first agreement was signed were in all likelihood much
larger than today's levels. But these 15 central banks have now
agreed to be bound by the previous limit, not the current one.
Therefore, these central banks want more room to maneuver, but
why? It's simple. Central banks are at war with gold because
they cannot in the end control it, with the consequence that
a rising gold price lays bare the dishonesty of fiat currency
and deceitfulness of central banking. Such openness would destroy
the pretence of honesty upon which central banking rests, so
central banks always seek as much maneuvering room as possible
to engage gold in their ongoing war against it.
(5) Note that the Bank for International Settlements, Federal
Reserve, US Treasury and US Exchange Stabilization Fund did not
sign the agreement - so all the major manipulators of gold are
not bound by its terms. So here we have 15 central banks announcing
an agreement that itself is a form of intervention in the gold
market, in order to give the outward appearance that central
banks and other international organizations are not managing
the gold price. And people believe it! But, you know what? There
is a loophole in this agreement big enough so that even the signatory
central banks do not have their hands tied by it.
(6) Central banks always like to leave themselves with an 'out',
thereby making it easy for them to avoid being tied down by agreements,
even when people think they are. For example, there is no mention
of swaps in this new central bank agreement, but swaps are routinely
used by central banks to convert their gold into national currency.
In other words, instead of lending its gold (the total amount
of which is restricted by the agreement), a central bank could
instead swap it, i.e., they swap their gold for national currency.
They accomplish the same economic objective as if they were lending
their gold, but who except those few people who understand and
follow the arcane world of central banking would know that central
banks could mobilize their gold in this way without violating
their new agreement because the word 'swap' is excluded.
Even less obvious is the absence of the word 'deposit.'
For example,
let's say I lend $100 to Morgan Chase. Now compare that act to
me depositing $100 in Morgan Chase. For all practical purposes
there is no economic difference between the two, as in both cases
Morgan Chase creates $100 of liabilities. Central banks frequently
'deposit' their gold instead of 'lending' it. For example, in
describing its liabilities, the BIS states: "Gold deposits
at that same date were." But no where in this agreement
is there any mention of gold deposits. So central banks have
not imposed on themselves any limitations for swapping or depositing
the gold in their vaults. This omission, in effect, allows them
to do whatever they want with their gold, while most people think
the opposite - that central bank's are limiting their activity
in the gold market, a deception which leads us to the next reason.
(7) It is better from a central bank's perspective to achieve
an outcome that makes possible some deception. Central banks
can then act surreptitiously, so that no one is the wiser. In
other words, let people think one thing about central bank intentions,
while the central banks are actually doing the opposite. This
result makes the central banks' market interventions appear all
the more powerful. What's more, if no one really knows what central
banks are doing, they can thereby avoid the embarrassment of
having to go through a show trial in testimony before Congress
or some other legislature explaining their actions. So not surprisingly
this new gold agreement has its 'outs' and deceptions as explained
above. Consequently, this much-anticipated central bank agreement
is not worth the paper it's printed on. It is just another underhanded
attempt by central banks to re-direct the focus away from what
they are really doing, namely, intervening in the gold market,
which brings us to the last and most important reason to ignore
this new central bank gold agreement.
(8) This new agreement is nothing but more of the same central
bank anti-gold propaganda that does ongoing damage to gold's
true value. To explain this point, the reasons noted above make
it clear that this latest gold agreement has a different purpose
than the one central banks would have you believe. This observation
leads logically to the following question: If there are enough
'outs' from this agreement so that none of it effectively binds
central bank actions, then why go through the motions? This agreement
serves the central banks' true objective, which is to make it
appear that central banks are more powerful than gold. While
the truth is that they are doing everything within their power
to keep gold from skyrocketing, this latest propaganda says that
they are keeping gold from dropping because they are supposedly
limiting their gold dishoarding. This propaganda is no different
from that regularly disseminated by them in the late 1960's saying
that gold would drop sharply once they stopped 'supporting its
price' at $35 per ounce.
By identifying themselves as 'players' and 'kingpins' in this
way, the central banks get leverage. Many people don't question
the central banks' intent or recognize their true objectives.
These people accept at face value and without question these
central bank pronouncements, but to do so is a serious mistake
because it is utter central bank propaganda.
This propaganda objective is the most important reason to ignore
this latest central bank announcement about their gold intentions
- in reality central banks are not all-powerful. Their power
only comes when people think they are powerful and therefore
as a result give central banks their deference. But the reality
is that central banks cannot control gold anymore than they can
control the price of a Picasso, which is what central banks fear
most. Only the market sets the price for goods and services,
so never believe a central banker telling you anything different.
James Turk
website: GoldMoney
email: alert@goldmoney.com
James Turk, the founder and Chairman of Gold Money, has
specialized in international banking, finance and investments
since graduating in 1969 from George Washington University with
a B.A. degree in International Economics. His business career
began at The Chase Manhattan Bank (now JP Morgan Chase Bank),
which included assignments in Thailand, the Philippines and Hong
Kong.
He subsequently
joined the investment and trading company of a prominent precious
metals trader based in Greenwich, Connecticut. He moved to the
United Arab Emirates in December 1983 to be appointed Manager
of the Commodity Department of the Abu Dhabi Investment Authority,
a position he held until resigning in 1987.
Since 1987 James
Turk has written The Freemarket Gold & Money Report,
an investment newsletter that publishes twenty issues annually.
He is the author of two books and several monographs and articles
on money and banking. He is the co-author of The Coming Collapse
of the Dollar (Doubleday, December 2004), which has been updated
for a newly released paperback version, now entitled The
Collapse of the Dollar (www.dollarcollapse.com).
Copyright ©2008
James Turk. All Rights Reserved.
321gold Ltd
|