Japanica!
Dan Denning
The Daily
Reckoning
Mar 5, 2007
The Daily Reckoning PRESENTS: Bennifer. Brangelina. TomKat. If the
global asset boom were a celebrity marriage, what would we call
it? Chimerican? Americhinan? Or how about...Japanica! Dan Denning
looks at the events of the past week and aims to answer the question:
Is the whole current global asset boom model in jeopardy? Read
on...
What's with all the over-reaction?
So a $130 billion was lost in China's market the other day. It's
not like it was real money. The sympathetic corrections in other
global markets were mostly occasions for profit taking by investors
and traders nervous about eight months of good times. All those
flashing lights and bells and whistles...those just mean we're
in a casino.
There are other explanations.
But we're not buying the theory that China's crash indicates
real concern about the sustainability of its boom. The China
boom is happening in the real world. The China stock market boom
is largely fictitious.
So is the whole current global
asset boom model in jeopardy? No. There are three pillars to
the global asset boom, Japan's easy money, America's free-spending
ways, and China's appetite for raw materials in order to make
things. If this were a celebrity marriage (with a bride and two
grooms, or two brides and a groom, or three brides, or three
grooms) what would we call it...Chimerican? Americhinan? Or how
about...Japanica!
Japanica it is, the new name
for the wobbly, triumvirate/mascot for the global super asset
bubble. And for the record, since we're sure history is paying
attention to every word we write, our bet is that this asset
bubble has miles and miles to go before it sleeps. The unification
of global stock exchanges looms in the not-too-distant future.
This will facilitate even more rapid global capital flows...and
bring even more investment products on-line for surplus savers,
be they in Australia, China, or Amer...er...Japan.
Seriously, you can see where
all this is headed, a super asset boom. And there's a simple
reason for it. The Boomer's (or Japanese and Chinese savers)
are not ready to leave the gambling table just yet. You, see,
they can't. They don't have enough money to cash out their blue
chips and call it a day. They are still making up for the tech
wreck, and still wary of the durability of home price appreciation
(and the liquidity in the housing market, which, at least in
America, is dropping like a stone.)
Was this week a wake up call
for investors that markets are still risky? Of course. But investors
already they knew that. They love risk. More importantly, they
can't afford not to take it. Day by day, we are inching closer
to the time when the Boomers will have to liquidate. But it's
not that time yet. So the money pours into the market, and the
market itself, facilitated by the merger of exchanges, grows
larger and ever more integrated.
You know what that means don't
you? The real liquidity crisis, when it comes (18-26 months down
the road, we reckon) will be much larger, much more destructive,
and impossible to contain. It will represent the end of the post-war,
post-Bretton Woods experiment with asset inflation as a means
to personal wealth-building. It will be nice to own some gold
then, preferably a lot.
The incredible irony of what
we've seen in the past few days is that most investors almost
always do exactly the wrong thing, from a rational perspective,
when confronted with "decisions under risk." This shouldn't
be that surprising, though.
Human beings, under the duress
of fast-moving global financial markets with dozens of virtually
untrackable variables, are programmed by nature to do two things.
First, they freeze, the way our ancestor used to do on African
savannah's thousands of years ago when they saw a big cat on
the horizon. You can thank the amygdale, which takes control
of the brain at these crucial times, pulling rank on the thoughtful
frontal lobes that otherwise makes us distinct as primates.
This temporary coup-de-brain
is nature's way of by-passing the frontal lobes to arrest our
action before we do something stupid like running for our lives
and attracting a lot of attention from other predators. Panic
does not promote survival. It's this freeze in our musculature
that gives us enough time to tense up our muscles and either
fight, or flee.
The second thing human beings
do when confronted with risk is seek the action which has the
largest possible negative effect on them. Yes, you read that
correctly. And here we apologize for getting a bit statistically
geeky on you. But as this is The Daily Reckoning, we are pretty
sure you won't read this explanation for market behaviour anywhere
else. From a novelty perspective at least, it should be worth
your time.
The explanation takes us back
to that crucially important year in financial history 1979. That
was the year Daniel Khaneman and Amos Tversky published the second
most cited economics article in academic history, "Prospect
Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk."
The paper was a landmark in
the understanding of human behavior because it pointed out the
tawdry little lie at the heart of classical economic models about
human behaviour, namely that people weigh risks with perfect
information and then make rational decisions. Wrong! Homo economicus
is a complete fiction.
What Khaneman and Tversky showed
is that people make two kinds of decisions with respect to risk
and reward, and that neither decision is rational. One the reward
side, investors tend to overweight certain outcomes, choosing
lower returns with higher probabilities over higher returns with
lower probabilities. Or, in layman's terms, most investors prefer
the appearance of certain, predictable, single-digit returns
from blue chip stocks or bonds than the higher but lower probability
returns from say, small cap stocks or emerging market bonds.
That investors would over-weight
outcomes that are considered certain isn't that surprising. It
suggests that capital preservation is psychologically (and financially)
more important to investors, than capital growth. The difference
today may be that investors-at least the retiring Boomers in
the West who make up the bulk of the market-need big capital
gains in the next few years to increase their retirement income.
This may cause them to take more risk (to make up for past losses)
than would ideally be appropriate at this stage in their investment
career. But you go to war with the Army you've got, don't you?
What's really shocking from
Kahneman and Tversky's paper is how investors approach losses.
And the conclusion is inescapable: investors seek it. Or, as
the paper puts it, "This analysis suggests that a person
who has not made peace with his losses is likely to accept gambles
that would be unacceptable to him otherwise. The well known observation
that the tendency to bet on long shots increases in the course
of the betting day provides some support for the hypothesis that
a failure to adapt to losses or to attain an expected gain induces
risk seeking."
And here we thought investors
were seeking alpha, and that global risk premiums were converging
toward zero. But no! What you're really seeing is more bets on
long-shots. This is, in the paper's own terms, a failure to adapt
to the very risky world we invest in. But then again, investors
are only people. And this means that in the coming years, we
can expect investors not to avoid wealth-destroying beahviours
and investment decisions, but to greedily seek them out.
Incidentally, Bill Bonner has
a theory about this, which he hasn't given an official name to.
His theory is geopolitical, that it is the nature of large institutions
(like empires) to find a way to destroy themselves, that they
must do so. Surpluses of any sort (financial, political, caloric)
are un-natural. Human beings, as every good student of Greek
and financial tragedies knows, find spectacular ways to squander
their good fortune.
Tversky and Khaneman show that
faced with a choice between a low-probability but high-magnitude
loss on the one hand, and higher-probability but lower magnitude
loss on the other hand, human beings tend to choose the higher
magnitude loss with the lower probability. Or, in layman's terms,
that means if you were faced with the choice of a certain loss
of $20 or the 30 percent probability of losing $60, you, if you
were like most of the other featherless bipeds on the planet,
would choose the 30 percent probability of losing $60.
It does make sense with a weird
kind of emotional logic. Faced with the certain loss of $20 or
the possible loss (one chance in three) of losing three times
as much, investors take the lower probability, higher magnitude
event.
But when you apply this statistical,
empirical, and psychological finding to the markets-and here
we mean equity markets writ large on a global scale, reacting
to one another in real-time-the result is stunning. It means
you can expect to see people engage in riskier and riskier behaviour,
nearly always choosing bigger losses over smaller losses.
"But wait!," you
shout. "You're forgetting about probabilities. Why choose
a certain loss over a probably loss?
Good question. But perhaps
our notion of probable losses is wrong as well. Investors are
operating under the assumption that larger losses in today's
markets are lower probability events. There is also a wide-spread
believe that the larger the markets get and more integrated they
become, the lower probability of really gut-wrenching losses.
The problem with this academic theory is that it is exactly,
emphatically, categorically, wrong.
The theory we refer to is that
market crashes are statistically rare and can be modeled on a
bell curve, with a standard distribution of price movements.
Most movements, in a classic bell curve, would be within one
or two standard deviations of the mean. Or, in stock market terms,
there would be only a few instances when the market produced
dramatically above average or below average returns. Most returns
would be rather mundane, and rather predictable. There would
be few crashes and fewer still triple digit gains. But the evidence
suggests otherwise.
"From 1916 to 2003,"
Benoit Madelbrot writes in The Misbehaviour of Markets, "the
daily index movements of the Dow Jones Industrial Average do
not spread out on graph paper like a simple bell curve. The far
edges flare too high: too many big changes. Theory suggests over
that time, there should be fifty-eight days when the Dow moved
more than 3.4 percent; in fact, there were 1,001. Theory predicts
six days of index swings beyond 4.5 percent; in fact there were
366. And index swings of more than 7 percent should come once
every 300,000 years; in fat, the twentieth century saw forty-eight
such days. Truly, a calamitous era that insists on flaunting
all predictions. Or, perhaps, our assumptions are wrong."
And what about this new era,
dear reader? When you combine Mandelbrot's observation with Kahneman
and Tversky, you get a picture of increased volatility and risk-seeking
behavior. People, faced with more to lose, risk ever more.
The only question now is how
large the stakes will get. And our observation on that is that
the global equity and asset pot has room to grow. Volatility
has been ominously quiet the last few years. It may have returned
this week through the backdoor in Shanghai. But don't expect
it to make investors more conservative and trigger a rally in
fixed income and bonds.
Rather, we may be seeing a
whole new level of global speculation, an order of magnitude
larger than anything that came before it. This game, the world
series of speculation, is the end-game of the experiment with
fiat money, money not backed by a real asset. But it would be
a mistake, we think, to imagine that the end-game is now.
The tragedy/comedy has at least
one more act and a few years to go. And in that time, we recommend
you pull up a chair, pop some corn (if you can afford it at today's
prices), and enjoy the spectacle.
Regards,
Dan Denning
for the Daily Reckoning
P.S. We do, however, advise
against over-weighting expected certain outcomes...that stock
prices always go up, that sovereign governments don't default
on their debt...and that investing for the long-term is your
best bet.
Just what is your best bet?
Cash in while you can, perhaps. Peace of mind makes being a spectator
more pleasurable. But, if you're in the markets, or must be in,
our focus will continue to be on the higher-magnitude returns
that are priced as if they have lower probabilities.
Or, of course...you could always
buy gold:
Zero-Downside Gold - Available
for a Limited Time
http://www.isecureonline.com/Reports/OST/EOSTG375
Editor's Note:
Dan Denning is the editor of The Daily Reckoning Australia. He's
also the author of 2005's best-selling The Bull Hunter (John
Wiley & Sons), and spent five years as editor of Strategic
Investment, one of the most respected "big-picture"
investment newsletters on the market. A former specialist in
small-cap stocks, Dan draws on his network of global contacts
from his new base in Melbourne, Australia.
You can buy
The
Bull Hunter
at Amazon.
321gold Inc
|